Public Revenue: Meaning, Tax Revenue,
Non-Tax Revenue with Classification of Public Revenue
Meaning of Public Revenue:
The
income of the government through all sources is called public income or public
revenue.
According
to Dalton, however, the term “Public Income” has two senses — wide and narrow.
In its wider sense it includes all the incomes or receipts which a public
authority may secure during any period of time. In its narrow sense, however,
it includes only those sources of income of the public authority which are
ordinarily known as “revenue resources.” To avoid ambiguity, thus, the former
is termed “public receipts” and the latter “public revenue.”
As
such, receipts from public borrowings (or public debt) and from the sale of
public assets are mainly excluded from public revenue. For instance, the budget
of the Government of India is classified into “revenue” and “capital.” “Heads
of Revenue” include the heads of income under the capital budget are termed as
“receipts.” Thus, the term “receipts” includes sources of public income which
are excluded from “revenue.”
In
a modern welfare state, public revenue is of two types, tax revenue and non-tax
revenue.
Tax Revenue:
A
fund raised through the various taxes is referred to as tax revenue. Taxes are
compulsory contributions imposed by the government on its citizens to meet its
general expenses incurred for the common good, without any corresponding
benefits to the tax payer. As Taussig puts it, “the essence of a tax, as
distinguished from other charges by government, is the absence of a direct quid
pro quo between the tax payer and the public authority.”
Seligman
defines a tax thus: “A tax is a compulsory contribution from a person to the
government to defray the expenses incurred in the common interest of all,
without reference to specific benefits conferred.
The main characteristic features of a tax are as follows:
1.
A tax is a compulsory payment to be paid by the citizens who are liable to pay
it. Hence, refusal to pay a tax is a punishable offence.
2.
There is no direct, quid pro quo between the tax-payers and the public
authority. In other words, the tax payer cannot claim reciprocal benefits
against the taxes paid. However, as Seligman points out, the state has to do
something for the community as a whole for what the tax payers have contributed
in the form of taxes.
“But
this reciprocal obligation on the part of the government is not towards the
individual as such, but towards the individual as part of a greater whole.”
3.
A tax is levied to meet public spending incurred by the government in the
general interest of the nation. It is a payment for an indirect service to be
made by the government to the community as a whole.
4.
A tax is payable regularly and periodically as determined by the taxing
authority.
Taxes
constitute a significant part of public revenue in modern public finance. Taxes
have macro-economic effects. Taxation can affect the size and mode of
consumption, pattern of production and distribution of income and wealth.
Progressive
taxes can help in reducing inequalities of income and wealth by lowering the
high income group’s disposable income. By disposable income is meant the income
left in the hands of the tax payer for disbursement after tax payment. Taxes
imply a forced saving in a developing economy. Thus, taxes constitute an
important source of development finance.
Non-Tax Revenue:
Public
income received through the administration, commercial enterprises, gifts and
grants are the source of non-tax revenues of the government.
Thus, nontax revenue includes:
(i)
Administrative revenue
(ii)
Profit from state enterprises
(iii)
Gifts and grants
Administrative Revenues:
Under
public administration, public authorities can raise some funds in the form of
fees, fines and penalties, and special assessments.
Fees:
Fees
are charged by the government or public authorities for rendering a service to
the beneficiaries. To quote Seligman, “A fee is a payment to defray the cost of
each recurring service undertaken by the government, primarily in the public
interest, but conferring a measurable advantage to the payer.”
Court
fees, passport fees, etc., fall under this category. Similarly, licence fees
are charged to confer a permission for something by the controlling authority,
e.g., driving licence fee, import licence fee, liquor permit fee, etc. Fees are
to be paid by those who receive some special advantages. Generally the amount
of the fee depends upon the cost of services rendered.
Fees
are a bye- product of the administrative activities of the government and not a
payment for a business. Thus, fees are distinct from prices. Prices are always
voluntary payments, but fees are compulsory contributions, though both are made
for special services. Sometimes a fee contains an element of tax when it is
charged high in order to bring revenue to the exchequer e.g., a licence fee.
Fines and Penalties:
Fines
and penalties are levied and collected from offenders of laws as punishment.
Here the main object of these levies is not so much to earn an income as to
prevent the commission of offences and infringement of laws of the country.
Fines and penalties are arbitrarily determined and have no relation to the cost
of administration or activities of the government. Hence, collections from such
levies are insignificant as a source of public revenue.
Special Assessments:
“A
special assessment,” as Seligman points out, “is a compulsory contribution
levied in proportion to the social benefits derived to defray the cost of a
specific improvement to property undertaken in the public interest.” That is to
say, sometimes when the government undertakes certain types of public
improvements such as construction of roads, provision of drainage, street
lighting etc., it may confer a special benefit to those possessing properties
nearby.
As
a result, values of rents of these properties may rise. The government,
therefore, may impose some special levy to recover a part of the expenses so
incurred. Such special assessment is levied generally in proportion to the
increase in the value of the properties involved. In this respect, it differs
from a tax.
In
India, these special assessments are referred to as “betterment levy.”
Betterment levy is imposed on land when its value is enhanced by the
construction of social overhead capital such as roads, drainage, street-
lighting, etc. by the public authority in an area.
Profits of State Enterprise:
Profits
of state undertakings also are an important source of revenue these days, owing
to the expansion of the public sector. For instance, the central government
runs railways. Surplus from railway earnings can be normally contributed to the
revenue budget of the central budget.
Likewise,
profits from the state transport corporation and other public undertakings can
be important sources of revenue for the budgets of state governments.
Similarly, other commercial undertakings in the public sector such as Hindustan
Machine Tools, Bokaro Steel Plant, State Trading Corporation etc. can make
profits to support the central budget.
Earnings
from state enterprises depend upon the prices charged by them for their goods
and services and the surplus derived therefrom. Thus, the pricing policy of
state undertakings should be self-supporting and reasonably profit-oriented.
Again, prices are charged with an element of quid pro quo i.e., directly in
proportion to the benefits conferred by the services rendered.
A
price is a form of revenue derived by the government by selling goods and
services of public enterprises. Thus, price is the revenue obtained from business
activity undertaken by the public authorities. Many public enterprises like
postal services run on cost-to-cost basis. The prices are charged just to cover
the cost of rendering such services.
However,
in certain cases, when the state has an absolute monopoly, prices having a high
profit element are charged. Such monopoly profits of a state enterprise are in
the nature of a tax. The difference between price and fee is this: the former
usually can never be less than the cost of production or service, while the
latter may not necessarily cover the cost of service.
Gifts and Grants:
These
form generally a very small part of public revenue. Quite often, patriotic
people or institutions may make gifts to the state. These are purely voluntary
contributions. Gifts have some significance, especially during war time or an
emergency.
In
modern times, however, grants from one government to another have a greater
importance. Local governments receive grants from state governments and state
governments from the centre. The central government gives grants- in-aid to
state governments in order to enable them to carry out their functions. When
grants are made by one country’s government to another country’s government it
is called foreign aid. Usually poor countries receive such aid from developed
countries, which may be in the form of military aid, economic aid, food aid,
technological aid, and so on.
Classification of Public
Revenue:
Different
economists have classified the sources of public revenue differently. A scientific
classification enables us to know in what respects these various sources
resemble one another and in what ways they differ. Of the various
classifications of public revenue available in economic literature, we shall
review a few important ones.
Seligman’s Classification:
Seligman classifies public revenue into three groups:
(i)
Gratitious revenue
(ii)
Contractual revenue
(iii)
Compulsory revenue
Gratitious
revenue comprises all revenues such as gifts, donations and grants received by
the public authorities free of cost. They are entirely of a voluntary nature.
Further, these are very insignificant in the total revenue.
Contractual
revenue includes all those types of revenue which arise from the contractual
relations between the public authority and the people. Fees and prices fall
into this category. A direct quid pro quo is usually present in these types of
revenue.
Compulsory
revenue includes income derived by the state from administration, justice, and
taxation. Taxes, fines and special assessments are regarded as compulsory
revenue. These revenues express an element of state sovereignty. It is the most
significant type of public revenue in modern times.
Dalton’s Classifications:
Dalton
provides a very systematic, comprehensive and instructive classification of
public revenue. In this opinion, there are two main sources of public revenue —
taxes and prices. Taxes are paid compulsorily whereas prices are paid
voluntarily by individuals, who enter into contracts with the public authority.
Thus, prices are contractual payments.
Taxes
are sub-divided into: (i) Taxes in the ordinary sense; (ii) Tributes and
indemnities; (iii) Compulsory loans, and (iv) Pecuniary penalties for offences.
Prices
are sub-divided into: (i) Receipts from public property passively held such as
rents received from the tenants of public lands; (ii) Receipts from public
enterprises charging competition rates; (iii) Fees or payments charged for
rendering administration services, such as birth and death registration fees,
and (iv) Voluntary public debt.
To
these two groups must be added another group to make the classification
exhaustive. Under this group, the following items are included: (i) receipts
from public monopolies, charging higher prices; (ii) special assessments; (iii)
issue of new paper money or deficit financing; and (iv) voluntary gifts.
Taylor’s Classification:
The
most logical and scientifically based classification of public revenue is
however provided by Taylor. He divides public revenue into four categories:
(i)
Grants and gifts
(ii)
Administrative revenues
(iii)
Commercial revenues
(iv)
Taxes
Grants and gifts:
Grants-in-aid
are the means by which one government provides financial assistance to another
to enable it to perform certain specified functions, for example, education and
health grants made to the states by the central government.
Grants-
in-aid are the cost payments made by the grantor government and revenue
receipts to the grantee, and no obligation of repayment is involved. Gifts are
voluntary contributions from individuals or institutions for specific purposes.
Grants and gifts are voluntary in nature and there is absence of quid pro quo
to the donor.
Administrative Revenues:
Under
this group, fees, licenses, fines and special assessments are included. Most of
these are voluntary in nature and based upon the direct benefits accruing to
the payer. They generally arise as a by-product of the administrative or
control function of the government.
Commercial Revenues:
These
are the receipts by way of prices paid for government produced goods and
services. Under this group, postal charges, tolls, interest on loans of state
financial institutions or nationalised banks, tuition fees of public
educational institutions are included.
Taxes:
These are compulsory
payments made to government without expecting a direct return of benefits. The
taxes involve varying degrees of coercive powers.
Canons of Taxation: Meaning, Types and
Characteristics
Meaning of Canons of
Taxation:
By canons
of taxation we simply mean the characteristics or qualities which a good tax
system should possess. In fact, canons of taxation are related to the
administrative part of a tax. Adam Smith first devised the principles or canons
of taxation in 1776.
Even
in the 21st century, Smithian canons of taxation are applied by the modern
governments while imposing and collecting taxes.
Types of Canons of Taxation:
In this sense, his canons of taxation are, indeed, ‘classic’. His
four canons of taxation are:
(i)
Canon of equality or equity
(ii)
Canon of certainty
(iii)
Canon of economy
(iv)
Canon of convenience.
Modern
economists have added more in the list of canons of taxation.
These are:
(v)
Canon of productivity
(vi)
Canon of elasticity
(vii)
Canon of simplicity
(viii)
Canon of diversity.
Now we explain all these canons of taxation:
i. Canon of Equality:
Canon
of equality states that the burden of taxation must be distributed equally or
equitably among the taxpayers. However, this sort of equality robs of justice
because not all taxpayers have the same ability to pay taxes. Rich people are
capable of paying more taxes than poor people. Thus, justice demands that a
person having greater ability to pay must pay large taxes.
If
everyone is asked to pay taxes according to his ability, then sacrifices of all
taxpayers become equal. This is the essence of canon of equality (of
sacrifice). To establish equality in sacrifice, taxes are to be imposed in
accordance with the principle of ability to pay. In view of this, canon of
equality and canon of ability are the two sides of the same coin.
ii. Canon of Certainty:
The
tax which an individual has to pay should be certain and not arbitrary.
According to A. Smith, the time of payment, the manner of payment, the quantity
to be paid, i.e., tax liability, ought all to be clear and plain to the
contributor and to everyone. Thus, canon of certainty embraces a lot of things.
It must be certain to the taxpayer as well as to the tax-levying authority.
Not
only taxpayers should know when, where and how much taxes are to be paid. In
other words, the certainty of liability must be known beforehand. Similarly,
there must also be certainty of revenue that the government intends to collect
over the given time period. Any amount of uncertainty in these respects may
invite a lot of trouble.
iii. Canon of Economy:
This
canon implies that the cost of collecting a tax should be as minimum as
possible. Any tax that involves high administrative cost and unusual delay in
assessment and high collection of taxes should be avoided altogether.
According to A. Smith: “Every tax ought to be
contrived as both to take out and to keep out of the pockets of the people as
little as possible, over and above what it brings into the public treasury of
the State.”
iv. Canon of Convenience:
Taxes
should be levied and collected in such a manner that it provides the greatest
convenience not only to the taxpayer but also to the government.
Thus, it should be painless and trouble-free as far as
practicable. “Every tax”, stresses A. Smith: “ought to be
levied at time or the manner in which it is most likely to be convenient for
the contributor to pay it.” That is why, after the harvest,
agricultural income tax is collected. Salaried people are taxed at source at
the time of receiving salaries.
These
canons of taxation are observed, of course, not always faithfully, by modern
governments. Hence these are basic and classic canons of taxation.
We now present other canons of taxation:
i. Canon of Productivity:
According
to a well-known classical economist in the field of public finance, Charles F.
Bastable, taxes must be productive or cost-effective. This implies that the
revenue yield from any tax must be a sizable one. Further, this canon states
that only those taxes should be imposed that do not hamper productive effort of
the community. A tax is said to be a productive one only when it acts as an
incentive to production.
ii. Canon of Elasticity:
Modern
economists attach great importance to the canon of elasticity. This canon
implies that a tax should be flexible or elastic in yield.
It
should be levied in such a way that the rate of taxes can be changed according
to exigencies of the situation. Whenever the government needs money, it must be
able to extract as much income as possible without generating any harmful
consequences through raising tax rates. Income tax satisfies this canon.
iii. Canon of Simplicity:
Every
tax must be simple and intelligible to the people so that the taxpayer is able
to calculate it without taking the help of tax consultants. A complex as well
as a complicated tax is bound to yield undesirable side-effects. It may
encourage taxpayers to evade taxes if the tax system is found to be
complicated.
A
complicated tax system is expensive in the sense that even the most honest
educated taxpayers will have to seek advice of the tax consultants. Ultimately,
such a tax system has the potentiality of breeding corruption in the society.
iv. Canon of Diversity:
Taxation
must be dynamic. This means that a country’s tax structure ought to be dynamic
or diverse in nature rather than having a single or two taxes. Diversification
in a tax structure will demand involvement of the majority of the sectors of
the population.
If
a single tax system is introduced, only a particular sector will be asked to
pay to the national exchequer leaving a large number of population untouched.
Obviously, incidence of such a tax system will be greatest on certain
taxpayers. A dynamic or a diversified tax structure will result in the
allocation of burden of taxes among the vast population resulting in a low
degree of incidence of a tax in the aggregate.
The
above canons of taxation are considered to be essential requirements of a good
tax policy. Unfortunately, such an ideal tax system is rarely observed in the
real world. But a tax authority must go on maintaining relentlessly the above
canons of taxation so that a near- ideal tax structure can be built-up.
Characteristics of Canons of
Taxation:
A good (may be a near-ideal) tax system has to fulfil the
following characteristics:
i. The distribution of tax burden should be equitable such that
every person is made to pay his ‘fair share’.
This is known as the ‘fairness’ criterion which focuses on two
principles:
Horizontal
equity— equals should pay equal taxes; and vertical equity—un-equals should pay
unequal taxes. That is to say, rich people should pay more taxes.
ii. But equity must not hamper productive efficiency such that
burdens should be provided to correct inefficiencies. This ‘efficiency’ criterion
says that it should raise revenue with the least costs to the taxpayers so that
tax system can allocate resources without distortion.
iii.
The two other criteria are: ‘flexibility’ and ‘transparency’.
A
good tax system demands changes in tax rates whenever circumstances change the
system. Further, a good tax must be transparent in the sense that taxpayers
should know what they are paying for the services they are getting.
iv.
A good tax system is expected to facilitate the use of fiscal policy to achieve
the goals of
(a)
stability
(b)
economic growth.
For
the attainment of these goals, there must be built-in-flexibility in the tax
structure.
From the above discussion, it follows that taxation serves the
following purposes:
(i)
To raise revenue for the government
(ii)
To redistribute income and wealth from the rich to the poor people
(iii)
To protect domestic industries from foreign competition
(iv) To promote social
welfare.
Important Characteristics of a Good Tax System!
To
judge the merits of a tax system, it must be looked at as a whole. For, a tax
system to be a good one just cannot have all good taxes but none bad at all.
The state cannot raise sufficient revenue and, at the same time, please the tax
payers.
As
a noted philosopher Edmund Burke once remarked, “It is difficult to tax and to
please as it is to love and to be wise.” In a tax system, therefore, different
taxes, good and bad may be combined together which tend to correct and balance
one another’s effects.
Hence,
it should be noted that a good tax system does not mean a perfect tax system
which contains only the good taxes based upon the canons of taxation, fetching
adequate revenues and causing no hurt to the tax payer.
A
good tax system is one which has predominantly good taxes and which fulfills
most of the canons of taxation: it must yield sufficient revenue, but cause
minimum aggregate sacrifice to the people and minimum obstruction to incentives
for production.
A good tax system should possess the following characteristics:
1.
It should ensure maximum social advantage. Taxation should be used to finance
public services.
2.
It should cause minimum aggregate sacrifice. In a good tax system, the
allocation of taxes among tax payers is made according to the ability to pay.
It falls more heavily on the rich and less on the poor. It should be reasonably
progressive so as to minimise the gap of inequality of income and wealth in the
community, thereby ensuring their better distribution.
3.
In a good tax system, taxes are universally applicable in the sense that
persons with same ability to pay are treated in the same way without any
discrimination whatsoever. In the Indian tax system, however, this attribute is
lacking to some extent. For instance, income tax is not universal in India, as
no income tax is levied on agricultural incomes.
4.
It should contain a predominance of good taxes satisfying most of the canons of
taxation. That is to say, the taxes imposed should be more or less equitable,
convenient to pay, economical, certain, productive, flexible and simple as far
as possible.
5.
The entire structure of the tax system should have built-in flexibility, so
that changes are possible according to the changing conditions of a dynamic
economy. It should be possible to add or withdraw a tax without destroying the
entire system and its balancing effect. A rigid tax structure is very
unsatisfactory. Taxation must cope with the changing needs of the modern
government. The capacity to adjust itself to the dynamic conditions of an economy
is a virtue of a good tax system.
6.
A good tax system should be a balanced one.
It
means there must exist not one kind of taxes but all types in the right
proportion. In other words, it should not contain just progressive, regressive
or proportional taxes only, but a healthy combination of all such taxes.
Similarly, it should have a balance of direct and indirect taxes.
7.
The tax system should be multiple, but then took a great multiplicity is not
desirable. Dalton, however, suggests that a good tax system has to be also a
reasonably efficient administrative system.
8.
Further, in a good tax system there is simplicity, implying the absence of any
unnecessary and avoidable complexities.
9.
A good tax system should not hamper the development of trade and industry, but
instead help the rapid economic development of the country. Taxation is
designed to mobilise the surplus resources in the economy and not deprive the
private sector of its resources.
Above
all, the most fundamental characteristic of a good tax system is the
appreciation of the rights and problems of the tax payer. A good tax system
must contain the majority of such taxes which produce good effects on
production and equitable distribution of national income and wealth. To achieve
the socialistic goals of public policy a good tax system plays a very important
role.
It
should effectively balance the weight and burden of taxation. The weight refers
to absolute sacrifice, in terms of purchasing power of real income surrendered
by the tax-payer. The burden implies the relative capacity of the tax-payer to
bear the tax.
Thus,
the tax system should contain taxes which are strictly in relation to the tax
payer’s ability to pay. In Dalton’s opinion, in a good tax system, there should
be a double illusion that rich should pay more than what they think they
should, so that the rich will be contented and the poor become virtuous; in
this way, the incentive to work and save will be sustained.
Various
factors have to be considered in determining the tax system of a country. The
tax system of a country develops according to the tax ideals of the government
and the goals of public policy, which the system has to incorporate in its
structure. The practical shape of the tax system of a country depends on its historical
background.
As
such, the tax system of one country differs from that of another, depending on
the institutional and historical differences. Nevertheless, as a guiding
policy, a good tax system in any country with any background must seek the
maxim of least aggregate sacrifice in its taxation policy.
In
a less developed country, the tax system should be designed for the
mobilisation of economic surpluses for economic development. Taxes should be
such that they help in raising the incremental savings ratio. Taxes should work
as a measure to prevent the flow of funds into undesired channels of
production.
In
the developing country, taxes have to serve as a means of curbing consumption
and tapping the resources for development. The tax policy in an underdeveloped
country should aim at stepping up capital formation and mobilising economic
surpluses through the diversion of resources from private consumption to public
investment.
Though
a tax system may basically be designed to reduce inequalities of income and
wealth, especially in a poor country, it should not conflict with the object of
augmenting production and providing incentives to work hard and save more.
Thus, the test of a good
tax system is its ability to inspire that confidence in the fiscal basis of the
government which sustains public morale and promotes productive efforts,
individual zeal and economic progress.
Incidence of Taxation
Taxes are not always borne by the people who pay them
in the first instance. They are often shifted to other people. Tax
incidence means the final placing of a tax. Incidence is on the
person who ultimately bears the money burden of tax. According to
the modern theory, incidence means the changes brought about in income distribution
by changes in the budgetary policy.
Impact and Incidence: The impact of a tax is on the person who pays it in the first
instance and the incidence is on the one who finally bears
it. Therefore, the incidence is on the final consumers.
Incidence and Effects: The effect of a tax refers incidental results of the
tax. There are several consequences of imposition of tax, for
example, decreased demand.
Money Burden and the
Real Burden: The money burden
of a tax is represented by the total amount of money received by the
treasury. For example, the consumer has to spend Rs. 50 more on
sugar monthly, it is the money burden that he has to bear. But if he
has to reduce his consumption of sugar it means there is a reduction in
economic welfare. This inconvenience, pinching, sacrifice or in short
the loss of economic welfare is the real burden of tax.
- Earlier Theories: The
earlier theories may be classified into:
(a) Concentration or Surplus theory: According
to concentration theory, each tax tends to concentrate on a particular class of
people who happen to enjoy surplus from their products.
(b) Diversion or Diffusion theory: The
diffusion theory states that the tax eventually got diffused in the entire
society. That is, the final placing of tax is not one but
multiple. The process of diffusion took place through shifting or
through process of exchange.
- Modern Theory: According
to modern theory, the concentration and diffusion theories are partially
true. Actually there are both concentration and diffusion of
taxes according to the conditions present. The modern theory seeks to
analyse the conditions which bring about concentration or diffusion.
(a) Elasticity: While considering
incidence we consider both elasticity of demand and elasticity of
supply. If the demand for the commodity taxed is elastic, the tax
will tend to be shifted to the producer but in case of inelastic demand, it
will be largely borne by the consumer. In case of elastic supply,
the burden will tend to be on the purchaser and in the case of inelastic supply
on the producer.
(b) Price: Since shifting of the tax
burden can only take place through a change in price, price is a very important
factor. If the tax leaves the price unchanged, the tax does not
shift.
(c) Time: In short run, the
producer cannot make any adjustment in plant and equipment. If,
therefore, demand falls on account of price rise resulting from the tax, he may
not be able to reduce supply and may have to bear the tax to some
extent. In the long run, however, full adjustment can be made and
tax shifted to the consumer.
(d) Cost: Tax raises the price; rise in
price reduces demand and reduced demand results in the reduction of
output. A change in the scale of production affects cost and the
effect will vary according as the industry is decreasing, increasing or
constant costs industry. For instance, if the industry is subject to
decreasing cost, a reduction in the scale of production will raise the cost and
hence price, shifting the burden of the tax to the consumer.
(e) Nature of tax: The incidence of
taxation will definitely depend on the nature of tax. For example,
an indirect tax’s burden is fall on the consumer.
(f) Market form: Another
factor determining the incidence of taxation is the market
form. Under perfect competition, no single producer or single
purchaser can affect the price; hence shifting of tax in either direction is
out of the question. But under monopoly, a producer is in a position
to influence price and hence shift the tax.
Distinction between
Direct and Indirect Taxes
A direct tax is not intended to be shifted, whereas an
indirect tax is so intended.
Taxes on commodities are generally called indirect
taxes as they completely or partially shifted consumers. But it should be
remembered that all the commodity taxes are not indirect taxes. A
tax is said to be indirect if its burden is shifted finally to the consumer.
Direct tax is the tax in which the commodity is taxed by the government,
yet its price remains unaffected or changed. In this case the tax
is not shifted to consumer and the tax will be called
direct tax. If the tax is shifted, the tax is indirect, otherwise
indirect.
Merits and Demerits of
Direct and Indirect Taxes
Merits of Direct Tax:
- Equitable, i.e., the
principle of progression is applied
- Economical, i.e., the cost
of collection is small
- Certain, i.e., the
direct tax can be calculated with a fair degree of precision
- High degree of elasticity, i.e., the direct tax can be raised much easily
- Civic consciousness, direct
tax creates civic consciousness among tax-payers
- Reduction of inequalities, i.e., the objective of direct tax is to reduce economic
inequalities by taxing higher income earners at progressive tax rates.
Demerits of Direct
Tax:
- Inconvenient: for the tax
payer to pay and file the income tax return
- Unpopular tax system
- Tax evasion is common
- Unarbitrary tax rates
Merits of Indirect
Tax:
- Convenient: for the tax
payer to pay and it requires no filing of returns
- No tax evasion
- Unified tax rate
- Beneficial social effects (in case of harmful drugs and intoxicants)
- Capital formation
- Re-allocation of resources
- Wide coverage
Demerits of Indirect
Tax:
- Uncertain
- Regressive
- No civic consciousness
- Inflationary
- Loss of economic welfare
Incidence of Some
Taxes
Taxes on Personal
Income:
- Income
tax, super tax and excess profit tax are all direct taxes and generally
cannot be shifted.
- However,
the business is in a strong position and can shift a part of his tax
burden to his customers. But this situation is rarely present
and the income tax payer must bear the burden of tax.
- If the
income tax is extremely heavy, it may discourage saving and
investment. However, it will mainly depend on whether the tax
falls on average income or marginal income, the effects would be
adverse. If the increase in tax is fall on marginal income, it will
mean a positive discouragement to the earning of that income.
Corporate Tax:
- Corporate tax discourages investment, level of national income and
employment.
- A corporation tax, by reducing the earnings of the existing firms,
discourages the entry of new firms into the industry which may result in a
monopoly or a semi-monopoly for the existing firms with all the attendant
evils.
- A part of corporate tax may be shifted to the buyers through a
price rise.
Tax on Profits:
- Some economists are not of the view that the tax on profit should
be shifted to buyers. It should be borne by the seller who pays
it.
- The second view does not subscribe with the above approach. It
is argued that normal profit is a part of the cost and when the
entrepreneur is able to influence the price, the tax is generally shifted
to the consumer.
- However, the tax on profit in the form of a licence duty will be
borne by the producer.
Wealth Tax:
- Wealth tax is imposed on value of a person’s stock of wealth
- By enabling the government not to raise the income tax rates too
high, the wealth tax encourages investment in modern industries
- Another obvious effect of wealth tax is the reduction of economic
inequalities by reducing the size of inherited wealth
Property Tax:
- The wealth tax is imposed on the net worth of the
individual. Whereas, the property tax is levied on the gross
amount of assets’ value
There is no shifting of tax and the incidence is on the person on whom
the tax is levied. However, the tax on productive property
- may be shifted to consumers.
Land Taxation:
- The value of land depends on two sets of factors:
(a) Natural
factors like the fertility of the soil, the situation of the land, some other
natural conditions, and
(b) Investment
of capital in drainage schemes, anti-erosion measures, irrigation facilities
and other measures necessary to increase and sustain productivity
- The tax on the first set is a tax on economic rent and has a
tendency to fall on the owners
- But when the owner can vary his investment when the tax increases,
he can shift the tax burden to the consumer.
Tax on Buildings:
- If the tax is imposed on the owner, he will try to raise the house
rent and thus shift the tax to the occupier or tenant. But he
cannot do this during the currency of the lease.
- A heavy tax will check building activity and the remuneration of
the builder and of other people engaged in the trade may fall
- The tax may fall partly on the owner, partly on the builder and
partly on the occupier
Death Duty:
- Death duty may take two forms, i.e., Estate Duty and Succession
Duty
- The Estate Duty is levied on the total value of the estate (i.e.,
movable and immovable property) left by the deceased irrespective of the
relationship of the successor
- The succession duty varies with the relationship of the beneficiary
to the deceased. It takes into consideration individual share
of the successor and not the total value as in the estate duty.
- Tax on Monopoly: The monopoly tax may be:
(a) Independent
of the output of the monopolised product, or
(b) It
may vary with the output, i.e., increase or decrease with the output
- When the tax is independent of the quantity produced, it may either
be lump sum tax on the monopolist or a percentage of the monopoly net
revenue (profits). In both cases it will be borne by the
monopolist and he cannot shift the same to the consumer, because the
monopolist is already on a price with maximum beyond which his profit will
decline
- In the second case, the price of the commodity or incidence of
taxation will depend on the elasticities of supply and demand, and the
influence of laws of returns.
- Taxing of the commodity, therefore raises the price which will tend
to reduce the demand
- If, however, the demand is inelastic, it cannot be appreciably
reduced and the tax will be borne by the consumer.
- If the demand is elastic, the consumers may buy less when the tax
has raised the price. Instead of facing a decline in demand the
monopolist may reduce the price and decide to bear the tax himself.
Commodity Tax:
- Taxes on commodities may take several forms:
(a) Tax
on manufacture or production of a commodity called excise duties,
(b) Tax
on sale of a particular commodity known as sales tax, and
(c) Import
or export of commodities known as custom duties.
- The commodity tax is tended to be shifted to the consumer and from
consumer to the producer
- Tax on production tends to raise the prise and will therefore be
normally borne by the consumer
- But the consumption tax is likely to check consumption and tends to
be shifted backward to the producer.
- Therefore, the tax on commodity will be partly borne by the
producer and partly borne by the consumer
- The portions of commodity tax to be borne by the producer and
consumer depends on the degree of elasticity of demand and supply:
Elasticity
|
Incidence
|
Elastic demand
|
More tax burden on the supplier / producer
|
Inelastic demand
|
More tax burden on the buyer / consumer
|
Elastic supply
|
More tax burden on the buyer / consumer
|
Inelastic supply
|
More tax burden on the supplier / producer
|
- As a rule, the consumer bears a smaller part of the tax when the
demand is more elastic than the supply
- This may happen that the price may not rise at all. This
is because the consumers have been able to discover an untaxed supply of
the commodity or substitute. In this case, the tax burden will
fall on the producer.
DD and SS
intersect at point P and MP is the price determined. Now suppose a
sales tax per unit is levied. As a result the supply curve of the
commodity will rise upward equal to the tax per unit. The new supply
curve will be S’S’. The distance between the two supply curves
represents the tax per unit of the commodity. S’S’ cuts the demand
curve DD at Q and, therefore, now TQ is the price determined which is higher
than the old price PM by RQ. Hence RQ is the burden of tax borne by
the consumer even though the tax per unit is LQ. Therefore, RL (LQ –
QR) is the burden of the tax borne by the seller or he has RL price less than
before (PM being the first price).
- Therefore the commodity tax is distributed between the buyers and
sellers according to the ratio of elasticities of demand and supply:
RL = Burden
of the tax on the seller (producer) .
RQ Burden
of the tax on the buyer (consumer)
Ed = Proportionate
decrease in quantity demanded
Proportionate
increase in price
---------------------------------- (i)
Es = Proportionate
decrease in quantity supplied
Proportionate
decrease in price
= Elasticity of
Demand (Ed)
Elasticity
of Supply (Es)
- In the above equation, RL is the burden of the tax on the seller
and RQ is the burden of tax on the buyers. Hence:
RL = Burden
of tax on the seller
RQ = Burden
of tax on the buyer
= Elasticity of
demand (Ed)
Elasticity of supply
(Es)
Sales Tax:
- The sales tax is levied on the turnover, profits or no
profits. It covers a wide variety of commodities.
- The sales tax may make heavy inroads into profits which may lead to
retrenchment in the staff and management, restrict enterprise and
employment and hamper utilisation of resources.
- Thus, its incidence may fall upon employees, management and
landlords.
Import Duties and
Export Duties:
- Import Duties are generally borne by the home consumer
- If the demand for the imported product is elastic and the supply is
inelastic and the foreign producer has no alternative market, then in such
a case the burden of tax may be shifted to foreign seller. This
situation is rarely present.
- Export duty is borne by the exporter. The price in the
world market is fixed and no individual exporter is in a position to
influence the world price.
- There are certain exceptional situations in which the purchaser may
bear the burden of export duty. For example, the supplier or the
producer has the monopoly of the supply of a commodity.
Effects of Taxation on
Production, Consumption and Distribution
Effects on Production:
- Production is affected by taxes in two ways:
(a) By
affecting the ability to work, save and invest
(b) By
affecting the desire to work, save and invest
- A tax on necessaries of life, will obviously affect the workers’
productivity and hence reduce production. A heavy tax on income
tends to reduce the ability to save and invest on part of
individuals. A decrease in investment is bound to affect
adversely the level of output in the country
- Normally taxation induces people to work harder, earn more, save
more and invest more to increase their income and enjoy the same income
after tax
- Some taxes has no adverse effects, for e.g., import duties, tax on
monopolists, etc.
- High marginal rates of income tax are likely to affect adversely
the tax payers’ desire to work, save and invest
- The reaction varies from individual to individual. It
depends on the individual’s elasticity of demand for
income. When it is fairly elastic, the tax will lessen his
desire to work and save
- Entrepreneurs may avoid the production of goods which are
taxed. There is likely to be a diversion of resources from some
sectors of economy to others
Effects on Income
Distribution:
- The effects of taxes on income distribution depends on the type of
taxes and rates of taxes
- Taxation of goods of mass consumption is regressive and
redistributes incomes in favour of rich.
- But if such commodities are exempted and luxuries are taxed, and
the taxation is made progressive, then the income will be redistributed in
favour of poor.
Effects on
Consumption:
- By imposing tax on a consumable good which is injurious to health,
its consumption can be checked.
- Similarly the tax on luxury goods can decrease their consumption
and resources diverted to the production of mass consumption
0 Comments